Banks have been boosting mortgage lending for decades, at the expense of corporate loans
Free exchange/ Economist
As safe as houses
Banks have been boosting mortgage lending for decades, at the expense of corporate loans
BANKS
may be frail and dangerous things, but most economists see them as essential to
growth. According to the centuries-old circular-flow model, which tries to
explain how money moves between firms and households, it is their job to recycle
private savings into business loans. That helps firms invest and grow. Places
where spare cash is routinely stuffed under mattresses, in contrast, will tend
to grow less fast.
In
practice, not all savings make their way into investment. For instance, as John
Maynard Keynes pointed out in the 1930s, it is possible to have “savings
gluts”—periods when households are more willing to save than firms are to borrow
and invest. Ben Bernanke, a former chairman of the Federal Reserve, has shown that scarred banks curtail their lending to
companies after financial crises even if they have sufficient funds, inhibiting
economic growth. But it is not enough for banks to be handing out cash: just as
important, a growing body of research suggests, is where the money
goes.
According
to a new paper by Oscar Jorda, Moritz Schularick and Alan
Taylor, the traditional view that banks primarily lend to businesses is out of
date. In 1900 only 30% of bank lending was to buy residential property; now that
figure is around 60%. Since the 1970s virtually the entire increase
in the ratio of private-sector debt to GDP around the world has been caused by
rising levels of mortgage lending. Corporate borrowing has remained flat. Far
from channelling money to companies, modern banks resemble “real-estate funds”,
the authors claim, in which long-term mortgage lending is funded by short-term
borrowing from the public.
The
same authors also find that the growth of mortgage lending has led
to property bubbles and financial instability. Their data suggest that rising
levels of mortgage debt are a better predictor of financial crises than surges
in other forms of lending. Worse, they find that financial crunches caused by
mortgage binges result in deeper recessions and slower recoveries than episodes
caused by other forms of debt.
If
mortgage lending is so risky, why are bankers so keen on it? The answer lies
partly in public subsidies for mortgages, which have boosted home-ownership
across much of the rich world. (America is one of the worst offenders, allowing
home-owners to deduct the interest on their mortgages from their taxes, as well
as insuring most mortgages to shield investors from losses.)
More
important, changes to international regulations on bank capital since the 1970s
have also increased the supply of mortgages. Under the Basel I rules, which were
first adopted in 1988, mortgages were deemed to be half as risky as corporate
loans; some national regulators adopted even more skewed risk-weightings. The
savings in capital this allowed brought banks higher rates of return on
mortgages than on other forms of lending across the rich world. This explains
why mortgage lending as a proportion of output has risen even in countries such
as Germany and Switzerland, where home-ownership rates have not risen by much
since the 1950s. It also explains why central banks the world over have found it
easy to stimulate mortgage lending since the crisis, but not corporate
borrowing.
Lending through the roof
So
how are firms funding themselves since governments and regulators tilted the
playing field in favour of home-owners? One of the fastest-growing sources of
funds since the 1970s, when corporate loans began to stagnate, has been bond
markets. In America, for instance, the stock of outstanding corporate bonds has
grown from 11% of GDP in 1970 to more than 70% today.
The
growing frequency of financial crises may be accelerating this change. Recent
research suggests that firms become more dependent on bond markets for financing
during downturns, as banks seek to shrink their balance-sheets. As Fiorella De
Fiore and Harald Uhlig show in a new paper, the
Great Recession would have been worse if firms had not tapped bond markets when
bank lending dried up. Whereas loans to American firms dropped from $4.5
trillion in 2007 to $3 trillion in 2012, bond issuance tripled. Europe and China
have seen similar trends.
This
growing reliance on bond markets to fund firms has both good and bad effects.
Capital-market financing may reduce the impact of company failures on the real
economy. As another recent paper shows, over the past 150 years in America,
bond-market crises brought on by rising corporate defaults have reduced economic
growth much less than banking crises caused by loan defaults. This is because
more of the risk is borne by private investors. If a bond defaults, the losses
are passed directly to individual bondholders. If a bank loan is not repaid,
however, the bank itself must absorb the losses. The insolvency of individual
investors does not imperil an entire economy, but that of big banks can.
Nonetheless,
as many economists have noted, bond financing is not always better in the long
run. Bond investors tend to prefer large companies with proven track records
over riskier small and medium-sized firms. That is worrying in a world of slow
growth. Historically, smaller firms have had the highest growth rates. They are
needed to drive technological innovation and improvements in productivity.
Subsidies
and regulations that encourage mortgage lending, in short, have the unintended
consequence of stemming the flow of capital to small firms, thereby holding back
the economy as a whole. And yet last year America’s federal government announced
that it would, in effect, expand its subsidies by insuring mortgages with
downpayments as low as 3%. The British government, meanwhile, expanded a subsidy
for those buying their first home. Such policies may yield political benefits,
but their economic consequences are pernicious.
Comments
Post a Comment